Last Updated On -30 May 2025
Among the basic ideas in economics is the law of demand. It asserts that, "Other things being equal, the quantity demanded of a good falls when the price rises, and vice versa." Usually seen and physically shown by a downward-sloping demand curve, this inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded is typical.
This rule does not always apply, nevertheless, in actual markets. There are few clear situations where the demand for a good could rise despite growing prices or decline depending on price cuts. For companies, economists, and students all alike to grasp, these scenarios are interesting and significant.
Under many ceteris paribus (all else equal) assumptions including constant income, tastes, and no change in the prices of comparable commodities, the Law of Demand In actual use, nevertheless, these disorders can vary. Psychology, status, expectations, and conduct also affect consumer behavior and sometimes supersede simple economic sense.
Though it is a pillar of microeconomics, the Law of Demand is not without exception like most laws. Demand can act against conventional wisdom depending on status appeal, consumer behavior, speculation, and needs. Knowing these deviations not only sharpens our understanding of economics but also enables companies, marketers, and legislators to more skillfully negotiate real-world complexity.
In a dynamic economy, knowledge of exceptions and mental flexibility in awareness of rules are just as crucial as their actual grasp.
Giffen goods are inferior products for which raising the price results in a higher demand, therefore breaking the law of demand. Usually basic for low-income consumers, such as coarse rice or wheat, these products bear names honoring Sir Robert Giffen.
For instance, a poor household might buy more rice to cover their bellies even if the price of coarse rice increases and cut down on pricey goods like meat or veggies.
Key Point: The growth in price's revenue impact exceeds that of substitution.
Named for economist Thorstein Veblen, these items are regarded as status symbols therefore demand more at more expensive prices.
For instance, luxury watches, designer handbags, and high-end cars become more appealing as costs rise, drawing more customers who wish to show off riches or social status.
Key Point: Social reputation shapes demand here more than utility.
Consumers may buy more now even if present prices are high when they hope prices will climb even more in the future.
Rising prices in real estate or the financial markets, for instance, often inspire panic purchasing or demand motivated by investments, therefore driving prices even higher.
Key Point: Demand is driven rather than by present affordability by future price predictions.
Some items are so engrained in habits that people keep buying them independent of price fluctuations. They are simply absolutely necessary.
Cases:
Lack of replacements or addiction keeps demand inelastic even with price increases.
Key Point: For such items, demand is inelastic about price.
Consumers sometimes link better quality with higher prices. When costs climb, especially for branded or foreign products, this view can generate more demand.
For instance, a customer deciding on a more expensive skincare product thinking it must be more effective even if a less expensive substitute is available.
Key Point: More than real price, perceived quality influences purchase choices.
Consumers stockpile items regardless of cost in times of natural catastrophes or pandemics out of concern for shortages.
For instance, even as prices skyrocket, demand for food basics, hand masks, or sanitizers rose during the COVID-19 epidemic.
Key Point: Normal demand patterns are subordinated to urgency and fear.
Indeed, in some unique circumstances. The law seems to be totally inverted for Giffen and Veblen products: higher prices draw more demand. These are, nevertheless, anomalies rather than the norm. The basic downward-sloping demand curve still rules most products. That said, policy-making, price decisions, and marketing plans all depend on an awareness of these exceptions.
For companies, knowing these outliers could be a strategic advantage. High costs are purposefully maintained by luxury brands to uphold reputation. Manufacturers of basic commodities have to take demand's inelastic character under crisis into account. Ignoring these exceptions might cause mispricing, poor inventory control, or lost opportunities.
Explore the world of commerce with our Latest Commerce Articles. Stay informed, stay inspired!
Response: Not at all. Though not all inferior commodities are Giffen items, all Giffen goods are inferior items. A unique kind of inferior product, giffen goods are those in which the income impact rules the replacement effect.
The response is that they are Veblen goods, hence greater costs make them more appealing since they relate with money and prestige.
By use of empirical investigations, consumer behavior analysis, and price-demand elasticity models. Advanced microeconomics and behavioral economics examine these exceptions.